table of contents

11/10/2015

Niklas Damiris on Money

Niklas Damiris is a natural philosopher, trained in biophysics, who has of late taken a turn toward social theory to investigate money’s role in organizing human existence. He is adjunct professor at the University of Lugano in Switzerland, and a visiting scholar at Stanford, where he recently gave a course on the philosophy of money. […]

download transcript [vtt]
00:00:00.000
This is KZSU Stanford. Welcome to entitled opinions. My name is Robert Harrison.
00:00:08.200
I'm coming to you from the Stanford campus.
00:00:11.000
[Music]
00:00:35.000
Six score and seven years ago, the hour was high noon.
00:00:40.000
Nietzsche's madman went into the marketplace with a lantern in his hand
00:00:45.000
to announce the news that God is dead and that we, the citizens of the modern world, were responsible.
00:00:53.000
We have killed him, you and I. We are all his murderers, he shouted.
00:00:59.000
The people fell silent and stared at him in astonishment.
00:01:03.000
Then they forgot all about him and carried on with business as usual.
00:01:08.000
Question. Why did the madman go into the marketplace?
00:01:13.000
Answer? Because that's where the transvaluation takes place.
00:01:18.000
That's where good and evil acquire their exchange value.
00:01:22.000
That's where faith, hope and charity get translated into money.
00:01:27.000
Behold, the transubstantiation of all values.
00:01:33.000
"Lashofiligah" money makes war. Napoleon once said,
00:01:39.000
"It makes a whole lot more than wars though.
00:01:42.000
It makes an unmakes and remakes just about everything these days.
00:01:47.000
That's why the madman went into the marketplace to proclaim the death of God at the scene of the crime."
00:01:54.000
[Music]
00:02:11.000
Money may not buy happiness, but those who have it hold onto it for some reason.
00:02:16.000
Turn in your hours for a handful of times. Go to your grave for a fistful of dollars.
00:02:25.000
Just how much do those seats in the Imperium cost?
00:02:30.000
[Music]
00:02:39.000
I have nothing against money, nothing at all, but just for the record.
00:02:43.000
I have never received any peculiar remuneration for hosting this show.
00:02:48.000
I have never paid a guess to be on this show.
00:02:52.000
I have never received any course relief for doing the show.
00:02:56.000
The rewards are all in the thing itself.
00:02:59.000
To Pragma Otto, as they say in Greek,
00:03:02.000
which happens to be the native language of my friend and colleague,
00:03:05.000
Nicholas De Meers, who joins me in the studio today.
00:03:09.000
Nicholas is here to talk with us about the history and philosophy of money.
00:03:14.000
I told you, you get it all on entitled opinions.
00:03:18.000
A few words about Nicholas De Meers,
00:03:21.000
he pursued his graduate work in physics and then turned social theorist,
00:03:26.000
investigating money's role in organizing human existence.
00:03:30.000
He's an adjunct professor at the University of Lugano in Switzerland and a visiting scholar at Stanford,
00:03:36.000
where he recently gave a graduate seminar course on the philosophy of money.
00:03:41.000
He's also the author of the genesis of economic value money as a quantum phenomenon
00:03:48.000
to be published by SemioText, MIT, in 2016.
00:03:54.000
In treating title, to be sure, we'll ask about that title of his, or subtitle later in the show.
00:04:01.000
Nicholas is also currently consulting for a research and development outfit in Silicon Valley,
00:04:06.000
working with other physicists on quantum social science, an emerging field that goes beyond behavioral economics
00:04:14.000
and social media analytics.
00:04:17.000
It's a pleasure to welcome him to the program.
00:04:19.000
Nicholas, thanks for joining us today.
00:04:21.000
Thank you, Robert.
00:04:23.000
Well, how to begin.
00:04:25.000
Let me begin by saying that I am not a big fan of Gertrude Stein.
00:04:29.000
In my view, she tried too hard to be a clever,
00:04:33.000
aferist and succeeded only very rarely at that.
00:04:36.000
And a case in point, she wants to clear or is reported to have declared,
00:04:41.000
like, "What distinguishes man from other animals is not language, not the opposable thumb,
00:04:48.000
not art, but money.
00:04:50.000
No other species has or understands money."
00:04:54.000
Well, no other species has or understands golf or newspaper ads or rock concerts,
00:05:03.000
but let's humor Gertrude Stein for the moment and say that she's right.
00:05:08.000
What in your view is so special about money?
00:05:11.000
What I think Stein was really trying to get at is that unlike other animals,
00:05:18.000
human beings have besides communication and family a much more complex form of organizing,
00:05:25.000
which is very much mediated and helped by the presence of money.
00:05:30.000
So in that sense, money makes human social life much more complex,
00:05:36.000
and I think that is what distinguishes them from other animals.
00:05:39.000
Well, yes, I'm going to take issue with Gertrude Stein and not with you,
00:05:45.000
but with your characterization of what she meant by that, because one can't say that money is endemic to the human species,
00:05:52.000
because for a long time before there was money in our history or prehistory,
00:05:57.000
there was Homo sapiens sapiens.
00:06:00.000
So it seems to me that as human beings, we existed for a good long time in our evolutionary history,
00:06:09.000
prior to the advent of money, and that therefore perhaps it's not as endemic to our species as she might make a sound.
00:06:22.000
In fact, let me ask you, we don't want to get caught up in Gertrude Stein, and what did she know about money anyway?
00:06:30.000
She had some of her own, she had some I know if you did.
00:06:35.000
But in at least in Western civilization, the first time we get any thinking, reflective thinking about money,
00:06:46.000
I gather is among the pre-socratics and Greece, is that correct?
00:06:50.000
I think that is correct, and I think this is also why the Greeks still have a lot of appeal to us,
00:06:57.000
is because there were the first who basically organized themselves in the so-called famous Greek police,
00:07:06.000
using money as a means of transacting both within and outside the police, primarily outside the police.
00:07:13.000
And I think unlike other very complex civilizations of the time, like the Sumerians and the Egyptians,
00:07:19.000
we can still connect with the Greeks of back then, precisely because like them, then we now also use money.
00:07:26.000
As very much part of our social complex organization.
00:07:30.000
Well, maybe the new Greeks are the Germans who know how to manage it a little bit better than the contemporary Greeks.
00:07:37.000
Yeah, I doubt.
00:07:38.000
Yeah, I guess.
00:07:39.000
They are not very pious towards their forebearers.
00:07:43.000
Apparently not.
00:07:45.000
So why would the pre-socratic philosophers, now we're talking about people like Thales, Heraclitus,
00:07:53.000
Anaximander, and Aximanes, and so forth?
00:07:57.000
What did they have to say about money? Why were they interested in money at all?
00:08:01.000
The basic idea behind the work of people like Anaximanes and Anaximander and Thales was to find out where something has started from.
00:08:09.000
What is its mode of existence? How does it come about?
00:08:13.000
So they each came up with a prima material, like Thales thought that everything was made of water.
00:08:20.000
Anaximander thought that it was made, it was the appearance of the infinite Anaximanes thought that it was air.
00:08:27.000
But basically all of these things were an attempt to explain a similar role that money seemed to perform in society at the time to be the substance that seemed to engulf everything.
00:08:39.000
And that was a pretty mysterious thing that something like money was able to transform or transmute something as air or water can do in the physical world.
00:08:49.000
So in the societies they were living in money was already a kind of general common currency that was in the first place.
00:08:56.000
It was becoming a fairly common thing, correct?
00:08:58.000
And you used the term prima material and then you also used the English word substance to describe money in this period.
00:09:08.000
Now, as far as I know, the word substance in Greek, Uzzia, which is such a huge, I mean that's an immense history in Western metaphysics as we know.
00:09:23.000
And in Christian theology and almost the substance of Christ, whether he's the same or of the same substance of God and so forth.
00:09:31.000
However, from what I remember, Uzzia originally belongs to the sphere of the household of the orchos where it is the substance, namely how many cattle or how many sheep you have and what are your actual goods, the substance in the most concrete sense of the term.
00:09:50.000
Am I right about that?
00:09:51.000
I think you're right about that, yes.
00:09:53.000
After the pre-socratic when Aristotle speaks about money in the Nicomachean ethics and the politics, the politics, Aristotle makes a fundamental distinction in his Nicomachean ethics between
00:10:05.000
Oriconomia and Crematistics.
00:10:09.000
What is that distinction? Is economy, Oriconomia, the substance that belongs to the household, the traditional household independently of money, and if so, what is Crematistics there?
00:10:21.000
Yes, I think Aristotle basically understood the household that's been a self-subsisting unit that was able to sustain itself and that was the whole purpose of the household's existence to basically take care of those who were supported by it and in turn, their work reproduced it.
00:10:42.000
So when the merchants started becoming more dominant, namely when the surplus from household production was needing a place to go, the merchants then used it to exchange it for money by selling it to some other town or to some other place outside the police households.
00:11:05.000
So this whole activity became pretty soon a self-supporting one in its own right, but it was now independent of the concern with the households' reproduction and well-being.
00:11:18.000
Well, relatively independent, but if a household was producing too much oil for its own consumption and the Crematists would come along and see if it could be some of this oil, I will take it over somewhere and I'll sell it.
00:11:34.000
Well, I think you are correct and Aristotle understood that, but also being a real Greek, he was also an ethical concern with ethics in everything.
00:11:44.000
So he somehow stigmatized this activity because he put more weight on what he would say going beyond the use value of things and emphasizing more what we could call what he also called the exchange value of things.
00:12:00.000
So that shifting emphasis is what he condemned, even though he is the one who made the analytical distinction between use value and exchange value of a good.
00:12:10.000
Well, what did he have against exchange value?
00:12:13.000
He really thought exactly that after a while you do not exchange one thing for another thing, you exchange another thing for money which becomes the goal of the exchange.
00:12:22.000
So the terminus becomes the money rather than another thing that you want.
00:12:27.000
So at that point, money becomes more important than the things for which it is exchanged.
00:12:33.000
Yes, but let's say a common senseical response would be, I sell my goods, I can't consume them all.
00:12:42.000
I receive in a currency a value that the value that they are worth.
00:12:49.000
And with that currency, I can dispose of it as I like.
00:12:54.000
In other words, I don't see what the animus is against the rise of a kind of merchant class which enables trade, commerce and flourishing in the market.
00:13:07.000
Actually, you're asking a very important and interesting question.
00:13:10.000
I think this was understood even by Aristotle, but at the same time the kind of merchant class that we are just describing is one that already allows for a certain form of individual to emerge.
00:13:23.000
Aristotle was much more concerned with the family and the police as community units that pre-existed the individual who takes the initiative that we associate right now with the merchants and the risks that such individuals would take in order to benefit both themselves and indirectly the larger realm of the commons or something.
00:13:43.000
Well, wasn't Aristotle getting paid for his services to Alexander the Great as a tutor or some other?
00:13:51.000
Wasn't what is under condemnation there, the very presupposition of the kind of police that Athens had become and that enabled philosophy itself to arise and liberate people from their bondage to the land as it were.
00:14:09.000
Well, I think this is again, as always, your interesting questions about the scene at the time.
00:14:15.000
In fact, the whole distinction between philosophers and sophists was exactly based on the sophists were those who explicitly did their educating practice on money on pecuniary basis, whereas Aristotle, not Aristotle only, but also Plato, were supposedly not wanting that or not wanting this.
00:14:38.000
As a reward for their services. They felt that the participation of the students in the academy was and supporting themselves, however they did, was the reason the academy existed in the first place.
00:14:52.000
So we've talked about use value exchange value and when most people hear those terms, they think about Karl Marx, and I know it's a big jump across the millennia to go from Aristotle to Karl Marx, but there's a lot that takes place in the modern era when it comes to the history and philosophy of money.
00:15:10.000
So what does Karl Marx contribute to this history and philosophy of money, but especially on use value and exchange value?
00:15:22.000
Yes, I think it is interesting that you bring up Marx precisely because I think he, we can easily say that he was the one who took Aristotle very seriously on both the distinctions that we spoke a minute ago.
00:15:36.000
In other words, he revived both the primatistic key versus economy distinction as well as the use and exchange value considerations and made them the central pieces of his analysis of them emerging industrial society in the 19th century that he we associate his critique with and his important statements with capital and everything else as based on.
00:16:03.000
He took a lot of his clues from Aristotle precisely because he thought that what is happening in the 19th century in the new economic world is that all of these familiar distinctions are changing, are overcome by something else, what he came to call capital.
00:16:21.000
So capital is not Uziya, it's not substance, it's something else, it's something distinctly modern.
00:16:28.000
Yes, and what does he mean by capital?
00:16:32.000
This is a very deep and controversial subject matter. He wrote extensively about it, of course the three volumes of Daskapital is the most famous.
00:16:44.000
He wrote before that earlier book in preparation of this De Gundrese, which was one of the texts I was discussing in my class at Stanford this past quarter.
00:16:56.000
And basically he was making an attempt to come to terms with the power of money as a force if you like in social life that becomes larger than any political or social mediated constraints.
00:17:14.000
So that is sort of his understanding of money as something that changes social life profoundly and when a particular class of people like the capitalist dominate, then a lot of others who are producing are finding themselves controlled by those who have access to this capital.
00:17:38.000
So, Nicholas, you referred me to it rather excellent, I thought a really terrific book by Felix Martin called Money, the Unauthorized Biography, published by Knopf in 2013, and I, in reading that I became very sensitive to how ambiguous is the concept of money.
00:17:59.000
So, I think that's a very interesting thing to be using money and capital interchangeably in your account now of Carl of course, the thesis theory.
00:18:07.000
But if Felix Martin is right, there is a distinction between those two because money is not, there's been money for many ages prior to the modern era and maybe capital is to be distinguished from money or is it, or do you just collapse capital into money?
00:18:25.000
No, I do not want to collapse capital into money, but what I think Marx was trying to do is to break away precisely from the view of money as some kind of a thing.
00:18:34.000
So, the emphasis instead should be on money and be in a form of relation.
00:18:39.000
So, capital is also a way of capturing the relational aspect of money, something that takes it away from its more tangible thing like characteristics with which we start in familiar terms, but then we find it very difficult to extrapolate how from such a thing.
00:18:54.000
You can move to capital instead is the other way around.
00:18:58.000
You start with them, capital has been a very intense social relation that money fast among other things through currency or whatever is the good that is used as money for exchange and payment.
00:19:10.000
By social relations, I presume you also mean class relations and class conflict.
00:19:16.000
Correct, absolutely, exactly.
00:19:17.000
Yes, both at work and outside of that precisely.
00:19:20.000
And Marx was extremely alert and maybe too alert because he lived in England to the class relations that they British society of the time and to this day has.
00:19:31.000
So, the connection between the proletariat, the middle class and the capitalist class was very much construed as a struggle among them, all of them fighting for capital.
00:19:42.000
That is, and its benefits.
00:19:45.000
And this suspicion or animus that he had against modern capitalism in its crudest form, what was it all about?
00:19:58.000
I think the surprise Marx and I think he's still a surprising thing and surprises and upset us is that he recognized that with the introduction of capital in all its forms, because capital more familiar definition of capital pertains to the physical goods to the
00:20:14.980
materials with which an economy gets started.
00:20:18.980
But now we can also extend these materials to knowledge and other skills that human beings bring to producing things that they then share.
00:20:27.980
But then the value that they create in this manner becomes something that is hard to know to whom to attribute it to.
00:20:36.980
So, do you attribute it to the worker who did the work? Do you attribute it to the person who invested in the project that the work was part of?
00:20:46.980
So, at that point, where did you attribute it to nature from which all the resources are right?
00:20:50.980
Thank you, exactly.
00:20:51.980
So, then it becomes exactly a matter of debating.
00:20:55.980
Where is the value coming from?
00:20:57.980
And once we find its source, how does that source share it with others who maybe have contributed less or more?
00:21:05.980
And so, for Marx, the primary source of value was labor.
00:21:09.980
That is one interpretation.
00:21:11.980
I'm not necessarily subscribed to that, even though I mean for now, I think that's safe to say.
00:21:17.980
The interesting thing is that the labor theory of value, which is how he's known, makes it appear that then money is something that labor itself is exchanged for.
00:21:31.980
And I think that is a misunderstanding. I think Marx wanted to say that the labor together with money create value, and then the laborers are entitled to the profit or the benefits that is collaboration between money and their labor has generated.
00:21:49.980
So, here again, like capital, you are using the word value almost interchangeably with money, and that deliberate I'm presuming.
00:21:57.980
Yes, correct. Yes. So, money value capital is how to value is a very enigmatic concept to share.
00:22:06.980
So, definitely. And maybe that brings us to a person who understood that very much, and precisely because these terms, money, capital, value are so interdependent.
00:22:14.980
He tried to somehow separate distinguish them analytically, a bit differently than Marx.
00:22:21.980
And he is here referring to Zimel, who was just more or less almost a contemporary of Marx.
00:22:26.980
And he basically decided to counter Marx's analysis by emphasizing value rather than capital, even though he understood, as we just said, that they are interconnected.
00:22:38.980
So, Zimel spent a lot of time in his famous book, The Philosophy of Money, tried to understand how value, economic value becomes the driving force of modern life.
00:22:50.980
How did he distinguish between value and capital if that was his response to Marx?
00:22:56.980
The way he distinguishes is that he thought that Marx put too much emphasis on production.
00:23:01.980
So, the emphasis on production was one that he wanted to downplay instead emphasizing exchange.
00:23:07.980
So, the moment you put the emphasis on exchange, then the place of money, as the means by which you facilitate the exchange of value, becomes more prominent.
00:23:17.980
So, he decided to leave out the conditions of production and the mode of production, and instead pay attention how value circulates, how values exchanged, and using, and look at the mechanism that enables that.
00:23:30.980
At that point, looking at money in the familiar senses of how we use it to pay, how we use it to credit each other, and so on, so forth, becomes the point of his analysis.
00:23:40.980
I've never read The Philosophy of Money by Zimel. Is it a fascinating book? It is a special relevant today.
00:23:46.980
I think it is still relevant today. I think it is, he claimed to be his special book, and he was very proud of it.
00:23:54.980
I think the interesting about it is that he, even though he wants to say things about the Ucia, as well as the chapter on the substance of value in the book,
00:24:06.980
I think he's ultimately the book becomes more a description of what one can do with money once it permeates the social sphere.
00:24:15.980
So, rather than looking at the origin of money or the connection in a more philosophical sense of how does money create value or contribute to value, instead he takes its presence for granted, and then looks at its effects, how that transforms people into Meissers, or into willing to go into an unknown area, just because they feel empowered when they have money.
00:24:36.940
They are pockets, and they feel rather weak when they don't. So, like, right now, if you were a refugee without money in your pocket in a inhospitable town, you feel differently from being there but having money in your pocket.
00:24:49.940
Zimel was describing the conditions of the urban life, and the money being the big motor behind it.
00:24:57.940
Certainly, money creates a number of effects that are not reducible in my view, either to exchange value or to use value.
00:25:04.940
Indeed.
00:25:05.940
Because there is such a thing as an economy of the imagination, with the economy of needs.
00:25:11.940
I'm reminded of a story in Bocatra's De Cameron, where a character named Landolfo Rufolo, who lives in the town of Rabelo, beautiful town on the Amalfi coast, very rich merchant.
00:25:25.940
But he's not satisfied with his fortune, and he would like to double it, and so he invests all his money in what we today would call perishable goods, commestable goods, goods that have a short shelf life as it were.
00:25:40.940
And Biza Shippany, and he off he goes to the island of Cyprus, and realizes that there was a glut there in Cyprus, and he was not able to sell his perishable goods, and so he basically almost goes bankrupt, and he takes to piracy, which is the other form of a capital.
00:25:59.940
And then he then finds himself captured by the Genovese merchants. Anyway, a long little mini epic, there's a shipwreck, and he's the only person to save himself by grasping onto a chest that's floating in the sea.
00:26:16.940
And then he falls unconscious, and the sea actually, the waves just take him to the coast of Corfu in your home country.
00:26:26.940
And there an elderly woman saves him from the water and brings him in, and when he wakes up, she gives him the chest, and lo and behold he discovers that his full of precious jewels, and gems and things of that sort, and being a typical merchant, he puts a price on how much that woman's saving of his life is worth and gives her a gem or something.
00:26:49.940
But then he goes home, double, double-eberish, then he was when he set out with a bunch of goods that are not commestable, and they're not usable, but they have some kind of value, the source of which remains mysterious.
00:27:05.940
Is it the value that comes from gold being the simulacrum of the sun, or because a precious stone has the eternity that might be associated with salvation?
00:27:18.940
Here is what Katra is saying that the economy of need is only part of the story, and not actually even the biggest part of the story, because the economy of the imagination is quite fascinating, and I think that might be an effect of the accumulation of a certain amount of capital in a given society.
00:27:36.940
I could not agree more, I think as a matter of fact, I would like to re-for from that, namely that precisely that you can say, money is once you separate it from meeting most basic needs, it becomes the thing that drives our imagination, and it becomes a force of the imagination in another key, if you like.
00:27:56.940
As poetry is one way in which imagination acts on the world, I mean, in language, you can say investing with money, and with the hope that your investment and the risks that you take will bring you something back is something that certainly money now as capital brings out profoundly and strongly.
00:28:16.940
At the same time, it also brings out the fact that the potential for value that the world has is something quite remarkable, and is on a par, if a paraphrase Einstein, with his remark that the universe, what is remarkable and miraculous about it, is that it's understandable.
00:28:33.940
And now we can say what is miraculous about the universe is also that it is valuable, and now we can say that the interesting thing about money is that it makes the valorization of things an imperative.
00:28:47.940
And from that point on, especially in the form of investment, it becomes a way in which you see that imperative, both that it's meanest and most effective as the case may be.
00:28:58.940
And is the traditional moral objection to that, that it is neutral, and that it can valorize the good as well as the evil and the weapons of mass destruction, as well as charities that it all traffics in the same promiscuous currency?
00:29:16.940
Yes, I mean, at that point though, I think unfortunately there are people who confuse the message with the messenger, and I think to blame money for that really means to misunderstand the very significant role that he plays in getting the thing of the ground in the first place.
00:29:34.940
Well, Nicholas, I'd like to go back to a few historical moments, and maybe you think that the founding of the Bank of England in 1799.
00:29:43.940
Actually 1694, yes, I'm sorry.
00:29:47.940
Yes.
00:29:48.940
This was a huge moment in the history of money, and you see in the Bank of England the precursor to our Fed and other central banks.
00:29:58.940
Absolutely.
00:29:59.940
Can you say something about that moment of the Bank of England's founding?
00:30:04.940
Yes, the Bank of England, which is about 300 years, a little bit over 300 years ago, which is not that long ago in the scheme of things, but still started the modern era.
00:30:14.940
And basically what is allowed is for the first time to have a very interesting balance between private interests and the interests of the state.
00:30:24.940
Because up to that point, the king would go out to fight and basically bankrupt the state, and wherever he would go and bankrupt, that his lords, they would not be able to get back to him for getting what he owed them.
00:30:41.940
The institution of the Bank of England allowed all of a sudden the debts of the king to become social debt to belong to the whole society, at the same time he was beholden to the society.
00:30:53.940
The society through its representatives who loaned him the money.
00:30:57.940
So it was a very interesting reproachment between the politics and the moral of the monarchy and the beginning of the new society that we associated with the merchant class and the ultimate leader bourgeois society that we know.
00:31:09.940
So does that mean that for the first time the king was responsible for his debts?
00:31:16.940
Correct.
00:31:17.940
And that he was a comfortable, a comfortable, a good act.
00:31:21.940
And we are still in this kind of regime when it comes to the relationship between the sovereign states and their credits and debts.
00:31:31.940
Yes, yes.
00:31:32.940
Because at the same time for a long time as you know the king had what is called siniorage.
00:31:37.940
In other words, he had the monopoly on issuing money which then he would cry up or down meaning he would determine their exchange value whenever he felt he was losing.
00:31:46.940
He would take away the gold that he was built into the coins and then he would collect them back and therefore he would allow others to inflate the marketplace with worthless coins and debt he would be able to have all the goods that people would still give him as taxes, as benefit.
00:32:10.940
So the king in essence was able to control through taxation and through monopoly of the issuance of the currency, the economy of the whole society that he ruled over.
00:32:21.940
With the Bank of England right now you have another institution that determines how money is introduced in the society and therefore who gets indebted and how the debts are paid.
00:32:34.940
And at that point the issuance of money and the power behind that is now maintained by the Federal Reserve and other institutions of that kind.
00:32:45.940
So I have a quote here by John Galbraith.
00:32:49.940
Yes.
00:32:50.940
Which you think is quite pertinent to this topic.
00:32:53.940
And he says the process by which banks create money is so simple.
00:32:57.940
Namely by the stroke of a pen, the mind is repelled with something so important a deeper mystery seems only decent.
00:33:05.940
Yes, I think this is a thank you for quoting this. It's a very interesting quote indeed because to go back very briefly to the history of how what did the Bank of England replace when it came into existence.
00:33:19.940
And you could say it replaced the previous money lenders in other words people who were keepers of the coins that people would bring to them.
00:33:29.940
Instead what in fact the make the bank interesting is the following is that he used double entry bookkeeping as a mechanism for over counting which allowed it to not only use the money that people deposited with it as something that it could then turn around and loan to other clients.
00:33:48.940
It also could use money that he was not deposited that's the stroke of a pen.
00:33:54.940
Some that he created with that stroke of a pen to loan to others.
00:33:59.940
So he was able to make something that look as good as money to be the same thing as the money that supposedly people deposited with the bank in the first place.
00:34:10.940
So this is an amazing slate of hand that was still live under and it takes a lot of thinking to I mean it requires reflection why banks have such a power.
00:34:23.940
How can they issue the stroke of a pen something that has value to begin with and why are there only ones who have monopoly over this activity of lending money when in fact others could be issuing money in the similar fashion.
00:34:39.940
Nicholas I'd like to quote from the Felix Martin book that you referred me to I find it very interesting.
00:34:47.940
He writes in his introduction quote money is not a commodity medium of exchange but a social technology composed of three fundamental elements.
00:34:57.940
The first is an abstract unit of value in which money is denominated.
00:35:03.940
The second is a system of accounts which keeps track of the individuals or institutions credit or debt balances as they engage in trade with one another.
00:35:14.940
The third is the possibility that the original creditor in a relationship can transfer their debtors obligation to a third party in settlement of some unrelated debt.
00:35:28.940
And then he goes on to say it's that third element that is vital because while all money is credit not all credit is money and it is the possibility of transfer that makes the difference.
00:35:43.940
So if you and I contract an IOU and I write you down that you let me $50 and IOU that $50 that piece of paper might mean something between you and I because we're friends.
00:35:54.940
But if you take that piece of paper and give it to Dylan and say well here Dylan IOU $50 this is an IOU from Robert he said no I don't trust Robert no but it's only when it's transferable this transferable credit that does credit become money.
00:36:12.940
Do you agree with Felix Martin that these are the three fundamental.
00:36:17.940
Requests for credit to become money.
00:36:21.940
I know actually I think these are all the three important prerequisites for money through as banking money as we currently know it.
00:36:31.940
In other words the quote of Martin's reveals in a sense his presupposition to quote back that all money is credit but not all credit is money.
00:36:43.940
The assumption is that money starts as credit and that is a questionable assumption.
00:36:49.940
So that is one that we can debate because the issue of how money is comes into existence as a unit of account is something that precisely as doubt brave says it's very problematic.
00:37:03.940
I mean what are you introducing when you're just making a writing scribble on a piece of paper you're not introducing a quantity in the familiar sense of the term.
00:37:13.940
How have you denominated something in terms of someone else will recognize as being a standard by which then you're going to measure value.
00:37:21.940
But that's why Martin calls it a social money is ultimately a social technology because it presupposes a society and he speaks about the primitive yap society where there is an agreement in a given community that this is going to be our standard of measurement for debt and credit and transfer the transferability.
00:37:42.940
of credit and so forth.
00:37:45.940
And that and what fascinates me in this whole debate is the terms that are used.
00:37:52.940
If you take even the word credit yes yes the word credit comes from the Latin credit it comes from it's comes from belief and you speak about the trust.
00:38:02.940
about the trust is another word for faith.
00:38:06.620
Absolutely.
00:38:07.700
Therefore, the credit system relies on a certain trust
00:38:11.780
and faith in your federal citizens of the kind of community
00:38:16.420
and the currency, the money, whatever form,
00:38:20.380
this sort of credit takes when it takes the form of money,
00:38:24.500
is something that always still relies upon a certain faith
00:38:29.460
or trust in the institutions in the community,
00:38:32.740
in those who have agreed that this shall be
00:38:35.620
a standard measurement of value between us.
00:38:39.500
Yes.
00:38:40.340
And that's, I think Felix Martin might be
00:38:42.540
on very solid ground.
00:38:43.980
No, actually, I think there's a confusion here.
00:38:46.940
I think Felix Martin confuses the faith,
00:38:51.940
confuses credit as something that someone has,
00:38:58.900
because he has been loaned money versus the credit
00:39:02.820
that has or the belief that someone has
00:39:05.500
in order to make something in two months.
00:39:07.500
So in other words, first of all, you have to believe
00:39:10.420
that something is a unit of account
00:39:14.260
that you're going to allow to circulate
00:39:15.900
precisely because issues of trust
00:39:18.220
and other considerations enter.
00:39:19.780
And then the particular object becomes stands
00:39:23.620
for the belief and the faith in your federal citizen,
00:39:27.500
not in the object itself.
00:39:29.380
And so therefore if citizens have faith or trust in each other,
00:39:33.900
well, if not in each other in certain kind of institutions,
00:39:36.740
noble and institutions, then the economy works
00:39:40.580
in ways that it doesn't work, if there is no such trust
00:39:44.580
and he gives the example of those months in Ireland
00:39:48.060
in the 70s when all the banks were shut down,
00:39:50.380
but that there was some kind of sense
00:39:52.580
that checks still had a value.
00:39:55.740
Therefore he associates credit with the,
00:39:59.780
that it needs a certain sovereignty,
00:40:02.860
where people in a nation or in a society
00:40:07.900
will believe almost unconditionally
00:40:10.100
that the credit system is as trustworthy.
00:40:13.340
- Yes, yes.
00:40:14.380
- And therefore he thinks that money,
00:40:16.780
the management of money or say the regulation of money
00:40:19.580
does have to hand over a great deal of its management.
00:40:25.260
Management too, what he calls the state or government
00:40:28.980
or because it's a social technology in that sense, no?
00:40:32.660
- Yes, but I think there are two issues here
00:40:34.580
that I think we need to be more clear about.
00:40:36.380
One has to do with money in whatever form
00:40:40.820
is the carrier or the expression of that faith
00:40:44.900
and believe that we have in each other
00:40:47.140
in the community in which is supposed to circulate.
00:40:50.380
And second, that somehow it captures a value
00:40:54.340
that then circulates and used by those who accept the form
00:40:59.340
by which it enters their transaction.
00:41:01.580
So the value aspect of money somehow mediates and the faith
00:41:06.580
that also requires for this, for its circulation
00:41:10.260
are too related by separate things.
00:41:12.340
- They are, but until a few decades ago
00:41:15.860
the dollar had a gold standard
00:41:17.580
and you could go to Fort Knox and trade your dollars in
00:41:21.860
for there were all these gold and bars.
00:41:24.420
And then that kind of nourished the illusion
00:41:27.820
that money was not just a--
00:41:30.580
- Yeah, I had a restaurant called it, yes.
00:41:32.580
- But that it had some kind of so-called substantial value
00:41:35.340
even though you can't eat gold,
00:41:36.500
you can't drink it, you can't build a house with it.
00:41:38.860
Nevertheless, we abolished the gold standard
00:41:41.340
and it didn't do anything really to interfere
00:41:45.220
with the system of exchange and commerce and credit and so forth.
00:41:51.300
So in that sense, where you put your trust,
00:41:56.300
I think is a crucial issue.
00:41:58.540
- I totally agree.
00:41:59.780
But I want to take off,
00:42:01.620
up from your last point about people still having
00:42:05.220
what I would call the atavistic beliefs
00:42:07.900
that somehow even if there is no gold anymore
00:42:11.140
to redeem the paper unit that you are having
00:42:15.500
or the plastic as you were using,
00:42:19.020
but still they believe that the value can be traced back
00:42:22.180
to this reference thing, the gold.
00:42:24.620
Instead, I think the real issue has to do that
00:42:28.660
if money, as we were saying earlier,
00:42:30.740
is something that fuels the imagination.
00:42:34.340
And in other words, deals with something that precisely
00:42:36.620
is the opposite of the tangibility of gold.
00:42:39.220
In other words, it opens your mind to potential
00:42:42.620
that is exactly not tangible in that fashion
00:42:45.420
and yet under certain conditions can become more actual
00:42:48.260
and more tangible, then these two possibilities
00:42:51.140
that you can in both cases, you rely on money
00:42:54.980
to get to is at odds with each other
00:42:58.180
and yet equally important.
00:42:59.660
I think right now we live in a world in which I think
00:43:01.820
thanks to investment and the way the financial system
00:43:05.700
has evolved where more using money or should be using money
00:43:10.020
are something that fuels the imagination
00:43:13.300
rather than supports some kind of a hoarding
00:43:16.580
of something that plays the role of gold of gold.
00:43:19.460
Yeah, it's a go out and chop you.
00:43:21.580
(laughing)
00:43:22.580
Well, I will not say something to that remark.
00:43:26.340
(laughing)
00:43:27.180
But are you a fan of Keynes?
00:43:30.020
I am a fan of, yes, of all the various economists
00:43:33.900
and I want to say this in the presence of
00:43:36.620
potentially my colleagues in Lugano might be listening to.
00:43:39.780
I think Keynes is probably the most important
00:43:43.340
and to this day, even though now he's ignored,
00:43:45.900
but he was one of the most important economists
00:43:47.940
of the 20th century.
00:43:49.580
Why do you think so?
00:43:50.780
I think because he understood now the importance
00:43:54.580
of money as a force in organizing civil life.
00:43:59.580
As a matter of fact, he made, and I would like here
00:44:04.020
to use his famous distinction,
00:44:06.140
he explained why do people want to hold money?
00:44:09.780
Keynes made a very important distinction
00:44:13.380
about what he thought are the most important roles
00:44:16.740
that money plays in society or the motives
00:44:19.220
that for people holding money
00:44:20.500
and what he called it the transaction motive,
00:44:23.740
the other one is the savings motive
00:44:25.140
and the other one is the speculative motive.
00:44:26.740
And the thing is that the different aspects
00:44:29.100
of phases of money or aspects of money
00:44:31.180
that we're using do not correspond to each of these functions.
00:44:34.260
What are these functions?
00:44:35.100
Can you describe them briefly?
00:44:36.260
I mean, yes, when the exchange,
00:44:37.460
when I talk about your transaction function
00:44:39.300
is there exactly when you use money to go out
00:44:41.820
and pay for the goods that you're going to be back home to cook.
00:44:45.780
When we're talking about your speculative motive
00:44:48.340
is when you have now stored money and it has stored value
00:44:52.260
which then you're using to buy stock
00:44:54.780
or speculate in the market or do things like that.
00:44:57.900
And the other one with the savings has to do precisely
00:45:01.740
what you're putting aside for the rainy day
00:45:04.300
or the excess that you don't use for transacting
00:45:07.380
and paying for goods.
00:45:08.860
- Yes, good.
00:45:09.860
One other character economist I'd like to mention is Hayek.
00:45:14.260
- Yes.
00:45:15.100
- And can you say something about why you think he's important
00:45:17.980
and who was Hayek to begin with?
00:45:19.380
- Yes, Hayek was a contemporary of kings.
00:45:24.100
He was like me, immigrants in the United States.
00:45:28.300
He arrived here at the end around the in the 30s
00:45:33.300
which was a very important time
00:45:35.140
because this was the time of the Great Depression.
00:45:38.500
And this was the time when Keynes was writing his famous book,
00:45:42.820
the general theory of money, interest and employment
00:45:46.340
which was putting in more or less setting the foundations
00:45:49.540
for government policy from ever since.
00:45:53.140
And Hayek now becomes important
00:45:55.540
because he had come from Austria
00:45:59.220
and from Europe which at the time was facing
00:46:02.820
the matters, the twin menaces of communism and fascism.
00:46:08.540
He thought communism was worse than fascism
00:46:11.460
because it centralized the decisions of how money
00:46:16.060
and other financial resources were to be allocated.
00:46:20.260
And this is precisely what Keynes was advocating
00:46:22.860
with a new deal in the form of the new deal
00:46:26.100
for the government to play a similar role.
00:46:28.860
So in the eyes of Hayek, Keynes was kind of replicating
00:46:32.980
this central planning mode of operation
00:46:37.140
that he felt was not adequate to the complexity
00:46:40.980
of the real economy.
00:46:42.100
Instead he felt that the best mechanism
00:46:45.820
for making decisions in an economic system that has money
00:46:50.820
is not to be driven by a central planning committee
00:46:53.580
but be the market itself
00:46:55.020
because the market has the price mechanism
00:46:57.420
as the term has it that allows people
00:47:01.540
to make decisions based on prices.
00:47:03.740
- So he was a free market capitalist.
00:47:06.060
He was the most articulate in my opinion
00:47:08.420
and the least rabid of the lot.
00:47:11.140
And he saw a lot of problems with it but certainly
00:47:13.140
he has become the patron saint by the likes of Reagan
00:47:17.660
and Thatcher later in the 70s and 80s
00:47:21.220
but he was very articulate of the role of the market.
00:47:24.220
- Well, the French thinker Bodhjia Jean-Bodhijia
00:47:30.140
is someone that you actually did bring into your course
00:47:33.620
here at Stanford when you taught your seminar.
00:47:37.460
But he's an unlikely kind of theorist
00:47:41.900
for you to put into play in this history of money.
00:47:45.620
Why Jean-Bodhijia?
00:47:47.420
- Yes, Bodhjia is indeed an interesting and controversial figure
00:47:52.420
and he was a social theorist
00:47:55.740
and he is known for a couple of things.
00:47:59.380
First of all, the critique of the capitalist system
00:48:02.340
and one of its byproducts, which is consumerism.
00:48:04.980
So a lot of his critique was of Marx, for example,
00:48:09.420
was based on the fact that Marx did not anticipate
00:48:12.620
that even the workers could become consumers
00:48:14.940
and consumption would become the driving force
00:48:17.100
of the whole economic system
00:48:18.580
and at that point production
00:48:20.540
that it was supposedly the source of valorization
00:48:23.060
in the previous Marxian approach
00:48:25.460
now consumption became the new force.
00:48:28.580
However, what makes Bodhjia more interesting yet
00:48:31.820
was that he got a lot of inspiration of another person
00:48:35.380
that I find even more important called Jean-Bodhijia.
00:48:40.380
Another French thinker.
00:48:41.860
- Yeah, we did a show on him here.
00:48:43.260
- Oh, you did, yes.
00:48:44.820
- Laura Whitman actually.
00:48:45.980
- Is that right?
00:48:46.820
Yes, but I of course, as you know,
00:48:48.460
then is a very interesting man,
00:48:49.980
but he's most interesting book,
00:48:51.260
which I don't know if you and Laura discussed on your show,
00:48:54.580
was the book called The Occursed Share.
00:48:57.980
And this is an interesting book that Bodhjia wrote.
00:49:01.260
For me is probably his best book
00:49:04.540
and it is a book basically about economics.
00:49:07.660
And I'll say a little bit about this
00:49:10.100
because Bodhjia was inspired
00:49:12.140
in this two-rightist book.
00:49:15.580
Based on conversations he had with a physicist,
00:49:19.500
the theoretical physicist, another Greek called
00:49:21.940
Zor's Ambrosinos.
00:49:24.340
And basically his idea is that an economy is based on access.
00:49:30.340
And that was rather than scarcity.
00:49:32.740
So this is a very important thing
00:49:34.860
because a lot of people to this day
00:49:37.420
imagine that the whole point of the market
00:49:39.260
and the way of a resource allocation, efficiency,
00:49:42.140
and all of these things are predicated on scarcity
00:49:45.180
being the driver.
00:49:46.700
Instead, Batais says no, if we live in an open world
00:49:50.020
in a world in which the resources that we know
00:49:53.500
coming starting from the sun are as plentiful
00:49:58.060
and endless as the solar energy that comes from the sun,
00:50:02.060
then that kind of economy, the only way to counter it
00:50:05.420
is to deal with this access by transgressing it,
00:50:09.060
by setting limits and overcoming them.
00:50:11.580
So you have a very interesting thing
00:50:12.980
instead of starting with a closed economy
00:50:15.220
that will always run out without ever understanding its limits.
00:50:19.780
Instead, you start with a world in which his open ended
00:50:23.460
is very rich and only by transgressing limits
00:50:26.260
that you set, that we set, are able to control
00:50:30.140
and live within our means.
00:50:32.420
I think that's a profoundly different approach
00:50:34.940
to the economy and Baudríja kind of understood that
00:50:37.820
by transposing these approach to the semiotic aspect
00:50:42.420
of present economic life.
00:50:44.780
- So finally, Nicholas, what can we expect from your book?
00:50:47.580
What contribution are you hoping to make
00:50:49.380
in this book of yours as coming out next year?
00:50:51.900
- Yes, I think in the spirit of what I just said
00:50:54.260
about Baudríja, I want to carry forward this view of money
00:50:59.260
as a symbolic system.
00:51:01.860
Baudríja basically claimed that the symbolic system
00:51:05.060
that older primitive societies were good at
00:51:08.460
and able to survive by, was superseded by money,
00:51:13.300
which has been by his lights and non-supportable system.
00:51:17.060
Instead, I'm claiming that if you really understand money
00:51:19.620
as a symbolic process, then some of the things
00:51:23.140
that he thought was impossible or are there only,
00:51:25.620
impossible for this system and only possible
00:51:27.460
for a more primitive symbolic one,
00:51:29.540
Karina also happened in a complex society like ours.
00:51:33.700
- So my last question for you is,
00:51:35.180
why did you not subtitle your book,
00:51:37.540
money a symbolic phenomenon, but instead you called it
00:51:40.780
a quantum phenomenon?
00:51:41.780
- Yes, because one of the things that I have learned from,
00:51:45.340
doing physics and interested still in physics is that
00:51:49.060
physics itself is the symbolic appropriation
00:51:52.940
of the world.
00:51:54.220
This is something that physics does not say
00:51:56.340
in so many words and yet that is what he has in common
00:52:00.300
with the economy.
00:52:01.700
In both cases, we're dealing with a symbolic mediation
00:52:04.660
that in the case of physics, we at least have a method
00:52:06.740
and a paratus.
00:52:07.820
- You mean mathematics?
00:52:08.660
- Mathematics and also other,
00:52:11.580
and some other symbolic structure, but basically
00:52:13.220
mathematics that allow us to perform this practice.
00:52:16.900
I claim that we need something similar
00:52:18.820
in terms of a method and a paratus to approach money
00:52:21.220
because a method and a paratus that performs a similar task.
00:52:24.300
- Excellent.
00:52:25.820
You get one guess on what song is going to lead us out
00:52:31.300
of our show today.
00:52:32.900
- I think it will be pink Floyd.
00:52:35.260
- I think you're right.
00:52:36.540
Take care, Nicholas.
00:52:37.660
We've been speaking with Nicholas Damiras,
00:52:39.620
who is a adjunct professor at the University of Lugano
00:52:43.380
in Switzerland and a course offer here at Stanford
00:52:48.220
and visiting scholar here with us.
00:52:50.300
I'm Robert Harrison for entitled opinions.
00:52:52.820
We'll be with you next week.
00:52:54.260
Bye bye, Nicholas.
00:52:55.100
Bye bye.
00:52:55.940
(upbeat music)
00:52:58.520
(upbeat music)
00:53:01.100
(upbeat music)
00:53:05.580
(upbeat music)
00:53:10.100
(upbeat music)
00:53:35.700
(upbeat music)
00:53:49.900
(upbeat music)
00:53:56.900
(upbeat music)
00:54:05.340
(upbeat music)
00:54:25.940
(upbeat music)
00:54:32.420
(upbeat music)
00:54:53.180
(upbeat music)
00:54:57.660
(logo whooshing)